What is the effect on supply when there is a improvement in technology and increase in excise tax?

The pandemic helped push corporate tax departments to increase their level of automation, raising their efficiency and effectiveness within their organizations

Automation has been cited as one of the innovations that has rescued most corporate tax departments over the last two years. Unfortunately, most automation was unplanned, as it was a necessary solution to being able to work over the previous two years.

Moving to automation didn’t just come about during the pandemic, however; according to the Brookings Institute, automation has assisted the way we work for more than the past 30 years, with businesses adding more automation after each recession in anticipation of staff attrition. It’s now hard to remember that the computer and internet has automated what tax professionals used to do with only a calculator.

Now, as businesses and their workers must again get used to the new way in which work is performed, businesses are faced with renewed focus on process and automation in order to build upon what has been started and respond to the Great Reshuffle. In addition, the increased need for the correct governance to comply with the continually changing national and international tax regulations. For example, the updates to the trade and transfer tax rules under the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and the Superfund Excise Tax alone are a strong motivation for increased technology and automation.

Corporate tax departments, like most enterprises, have “a pretty good idea” of their business processes and desired outcomes. However, having an idea isn’t enough. Business processes must be thoroughly thought out with the idea of how it should be customized to the department. A business process or workflow must include at a minimum the following steps:

      • events and activities that occur within a workflow;
      • the owner or initiator of those events and activities;
      • decision points and the different paths workflows can take based on their outcomes;
      • devices involved in the process;
      • timelines of the overall process and each step in the process; and
      • success and failure rates of the process.

The tax department team can create the business process model before working with IT on the creation of the business process itself, allowing for clarity and the ability to fine-tune what technologies and systems should be employed for automation. Having the business process as the roadmap to automation doesn’t mean perfect is the immediate outcome. To be thoughtful and thorough requires fine-tuning to get to where the team needs to be, and so below are some considerations department leaders need to think about when automating their tax department successfully.

1. Start with the basics, the beginning of what the tax function’s operational role is within the organization — According to a KPMG’s Global Tax Benchmarking report, most tax departments are responsible for such task as: i) tax returns and compliance; ii) business unit support and consulting; iii) transaction taxes; iv) accounting for income taxes; and v) transfer pricing. In addition, the report highlights that “the most effective, highly valued tax departments are those that manage tax risk and compliance while identifying opportunities for adding value through core tax management skills.” This may seem obvious, but clarifying and reclarifying the role of the tax team in how it supports the overall organization is the foundation of what the department should do. Focusing on this will help determine what areas can and should be automated; and this is especially true as leaders consider what tasks needs to be automated so that resources can be freed up for other opportunities.

2. After identifying areas where automation is needed, clearly state the expected outcomes from the implementation of automation — Again, it is a seemingly simple step that is often overlooked, yet ignoring it could lead to failure to adapt to the new process or early abandonment of a new innovation because people believe it isn’t working. Many organizations begin their automation journey by setting a broad mission to drive productivity across the business, hoping it will lead to cost savings or some other miracle savings, such as in time or other resources. It is necessary, not critical, that those involved in the automation decisions state their expectation of what the automation will solve and then establish a timeline for that outcome.

3. Who will do what? Understanding the current skillset and bandwidth of your team — Another common mistake is believing everyone on the team needs to be trained on the new technology. Unless it truly impacts or changes the job of everyone on the team, don’t do it. It is wasteful to train someone on something they may never or rarely use. Return the team’s focus to aligning with the targeted outcome, and those that will work on the technology will be trained. And remember, it may not be a bad idea to ask workers if they are interested in this training or whether they would want to work on some other job function that may not require the training — this too may help minimize adoption failure.

4. Now you have not only pinpointed the technology and the accompanying talent, but created a roadmap — The automation roadmap is key to identifying specific parameters and benchmarks for the process. This roadmap should include tight timelines such as three to six months from its start over a period of time. Because technology changes so rapidly, using this approach helps measure whether the tools you have are still working. Of course, this doesn’t mean technologies may need to be replaced, it could be as simple as making sure your team is working on the last version of the software or technologies you own. The roadmap can also provide opportunities to review the skills and talents of those working on the technology and determine whether they are still the right fit or if additional training or even new hires may be needed.

Eventually, tax teams will work with tax technologists or the company’s IT team, but tax department leaders will need to drive the initiation or expansion of automation in the tax department. As a business leader and advisor to the business, tax team leaders need to ensure that the processes and automation undertaken can make the tax team better at managing risk and delivering value to the business.

  • What is the effect on supply when there is a improvement in technology and increase in excise tax?
    Access through your institution

What is the effect on supply when there is a improvement in technology and increase in excise tax?

Volume 47, Issue 5, June 2018, Pages 854-871

What is the effect on supply when there is a improvement in technology and increase in excise tax?

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2018.02.010Get rights and content

When the Affordable Care Act (ACA) was enacted on March 23, 2010, the federal government included a 2.3% excise tax on medical devices to help cover the costs of the expanded health insurance coverage. Medical device manufacturers criticized this excise tax, insisting that the tax would harm their research and development (R&D) investment and performance and thus should be abolished (Gravelle and Lowry, 2014). According to a Research America (2016) report, total R&D spending in medical and health care industries was $158.7 billion in 2015, with the medical device industry as one of the top five R&D-intensive industries. One of the largest medical device manufacturers, Stryker Corporation, estimated that this new excise tax would cost it approximately $100 million in 2013. Yet no prior study has examined whether the medical device excise tax affects firms’ R&D investment and performance in a negative way. In this article, I thus investigate how the excise tax affects R&D investment and various performance metrics (i.e. sales revenue, gross margins, and earnings) for medical device firms.

The excise tax could affect the medical device industry in different ways. On the one hand, the statutory incidence of the medical device tax on firms could increase the cost of production and shift the market supply curve upward. Then, the tax incidence would reduce firm sales, profits, and R&D investment if the price elasticity of market supply was relatively lower than market demand. On the other hand, if medical device manufacturers have high price elasticity with respect to the tax, they could pass the excise tax to consumers through prices (i.e. the tax is “passed forward”) and keep their original profits and margins. Therefore, the effects of the medical device tax on firm R&D and performance could differ depending on the elasticity of supply and demand for medical devices (Harberger, 1962), which is worthwhile to investigate empirically.

To identify the effects of the medical device tax on firm R&D investment and performance, I use the difference-in-differences (DD) framework. Specifically, I compare a treatment group of firms producing medical devices with a control group of high-tech firms producing non-medical devices, such as pharmaceutical products (Barry, 2005; Wolf and Terrell, 2016), before and after the excise tax incidence. For the empirical analysis, this article focuses on four different types of firm-level variables: (1) R&D expenditures, (2) sales revenue, (3) gross margins, and (4) earnings (profits). Analyzing the COMPUSTAT data from 2006 to 2015, I find that the medical device tax significantly reduced R&D expenditures, sales revenue, gross margins, and earnings by approximately $34 million, $188 million, $375 million, and $68 million, respectively, for firms in the treatment group.

In addition, the empirical findings suggest that the excise tax affected operating costs and market strategies for medical device manufacturers. These firms reduced their operating costs to alleviate the excise tax burden. They also significantly increased the global market sales intensity (i.e. the degree to which their sales revenue comes from operations in foreign countries) and global market diversification (i.e. the degree to which they diversified their businesses across different foreign markets) after the tax incidence because medical device sales outside the United States are tax-exempt. Furthermore, these firms increased customer market diversification (i.e. the degree to which they diversified their major customers in the United States) in an effort to reduce market power of major customers, to facilitate the passing of the excise tax to consumers through price.

This article contributes to the literature in two major ways. First, to the best of my knowledge, this article is the first to assess the effects of the medical device tax on firm performance and R&D investment. One recent study (Schmutz and Santerre, 2013) forecasted how much the excise tax would reduce R&D spending in the medical device industry. This article differs in the way it estimates the ex-post causal effects of the excise tax on firm performance in addition to R&D investment. As the medical device industry is highly R&D intensive and R&D is a primary driver of firm productivity and economic growth (Minniti and Venturini, 2017; Siliverstovs, 2016), it is critical to understand how the government tax policy affects firm performance in the R&D-intensive industry. Yet previous research has mostly focused on investigating the impact of R&D subsidies or tax credits on R&D investment in non-medical device manufacturing industries (Bloom et al., 2002; Bronzini and Iachini, 2014; Czarnitzki et al., 2011) or the pharmaceutical industry (Grabowski and Vernon, 2000; Scherer, 2001; Vernon, 2005).

Second, as the medical device market has not previously been subject to an excise tax, the estimation results in this article help clarify how medical device firms respond to the ad valorem excise tax and pass their tax burdens to customers. In particular, the empirical findings for the reduction in firm gross margins due to the excise tax suggest that firms in the medical device industry cannot fully pass the tax to consumers through prices, and therefore they reduce their operating costs to alleviate the excise tax burden. In addition, in contrast with other government policies, such as R&D subsidy or tax credit programs, the sample firms in this study do not suffer from a self-selection bias from participating in government programs, because the ACA excise tax is applied to all manufacturers, producers, and importers in the US medical device industry.

The rest of this article proceeds as follows: Section 2 explains the introduction of the medical device tax by the ACA, reviews previous literature on the effects of government tax policy on firm R&D, and demonstrates how the medical device tax affects firm R&D investment and performance. Section 3 describes the COMPUSTAT data and presents the descriptive statistics of the sample. Section 4 establishes the empirical strategy for identifying the effects of the medical device tax on firm R&D investment and performance and presents the empirical results. Section 5 provides concluding remarks.

The ACA, also known as “Obamacare,” was signed into law by the former US president Barack Obama on March 23, 2010. It included three key mandate provisions (i.e. employer, individual, and dependent coverage) to expand health insurance coverage to universal levels. To help cover the costs of the expanded health insurance coverage, the ACA also included several new taxes and fees imposed on several sectors.1

To examine how the medical device tax affected firm R&D investment and performance, I use the COMPUSTAT data from 2006 to 2015, which covers the periods before and after the tax incidence by the ACA.9

To analyze the effects of the medical device tax on firm R&D and performance, I use a standard DD framework. For the identification strategy, I compare the medical device manufacturers with firms producing pharmaceutical products, ophthalmic goods, and hearing aids before and after the tax incidence in 2013. Under this DD framework, I estimate the following model:yi,j,t=α1I(Med.Device)·I(Post2013)+α2I(Med.Device)+α3I(Post2013)+Xi,j,t'α4+Tt'α5+ϑj'α6+εi,j,t,where yi,j,t is the R&D expenditure

This study examines how the medical device excise tax affects firm R&D investment and performance. Using the DD framework as the identification strategy, I compared R&D investment and performance (i.e. sales revenue, gross margins, earnings, ROE, ROA, and Tobin’s q) for firms in the medical device and other high-tech industries before and after the tax incidence in 2013. The empirical results suggest that the ACA medical device tax significantly reduced R&D investment, sales revenue, gross

The author thanks Neil Bruce, Terry Shevlin, Stephen Turnovsky, Jun-Koo Kang, Eric Zivot, Seik Kim, Ju-Yeon Lee, Laura Jolly, David Spalding, Carl Weems, Jonathan Fox, Jennifer Margrett, Carla Peterson, and attendees of the public finance and corporate finance seminars at the University of Washington, Iowa State University, KAIST, and Peking University for their valuable comments. The author also thanks the editor and the anonymous reviewers for their constructive feedback.

  • C. Paunov
  • A. Minniti et al.
  • W.W. McCutchen
  • C.-Y. Lee
  • D. Lee et al.
  • J.E. Harris
  • B. Hall et al.
  • J. García-Quevedo et al.
  • D. Fullerton et al.
  • P. DeCicca et al.

  • D. Czarnitzki et al.
  • D. Chor et al.
  • N. Bloom et al.
  • F. Barry
  • C. Ai et al.
  • P. Aghion et al.
  • P. Aghion et al.
  • P. Aghion et al.
  • S. Arvanitis et al.
  • G. Barlevy
  • T.J. Besley et al.
  • N. Bloom
  • R. Blundell et al.
  • R. Bronzini et al.
  • M. Cincera et al.
  • W.M. Cohen et al.
  • L.M. D’Agostino et al.
  • A.K. Dixit et al.
    • Industrial enterprises are the main body of national scientific and technological innovation activities, and the improvement of their research and development (R&D) output capacity plays a pivotal role in the enhancement of national innovation capabilities. The R&D process is an input–output process, and its results have various forms. In this study, we construct a multi-objective R&D investment allocation optimization model from three dimensions representing China’s innovation capability, and propose a novel multi-objective mutation flower pollination algorithm (MOMFPA) to solve the model. We employ a two paired-sample T-tests to test the difference hypothesis of the model, and the test results show that the model is effective and reasonable. The MOMFPA and the weighting algorithm are respectively used for empirical analysis, and the optimized results obtained by the MOMFPA are found to be better than those obtained by the weighting algorithm, thereby demonstrating the validity and application value of the MOMFPA. Moreover, the multi-objective model is used to predictively optimize China’s future R&D investment. The forecasting results indicate that China should focus on increasing the proportions of R&D investment in high-tech equipment manufacturing and electronic information technology, while reducing the proportions of R&D investment in traditional industries, such as mining, food, paper, and metallurgy.

    • Using a sample of Chinese listed firms in new energy vehicle industry over the period of 2007 to 2018, we examine the impact of trade policy uncertainty on corporate innovation. We find that uncertainty concerning trade policy is positively associated with more R&D and patents. Moreover, government subsidy and managerial ownership mitigate the strength of the relation between trade policy uncertainty and corporate innovation. Our conclusions are robust to a variety of sensitivity tests and we use two-stage least squares (2SLS) instrumental variable approach to address the potential endogeneity concerns.

    • This paper explores the determinants of the development of the new energy vehicles (NEVs) industry in China, which is important to the government in controlling the environmental pollution associated with the urbanization process. Urban governance policies have played an important role in promoting the sustainable development of cities. In this study, we investigate the dynamic effects of such policies and of financial support on the relationship between firm size and efficiency in the NEVs industry. These policies include subsidies from state and local governments during the production and promotion of NEVs. The sample includes an unbalanced panel data set of 148 firms closely related to the automobile industry in the Zhongguancun Science Park from 2005 to 2015. A data envelopment analysis model and a random effects model are used to test the hypotheses, and the results show that both government policies and financial support are beneficial in increasing the efficiency of large NEVs firms. However, small firms cannot benefit from these policies. To promote the technological progress of the NEVs industry, it is highly important to provide further government support for the small NEVs firms that play a leading role in the development of emerging technologies. Only in this way can the government create a healthy market environment for the future of NEVs industry, and reduce the pollution in urban areas.

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    • When seeking to improve science in emerging economies, uncertainty exists whether PhD training in an emerging economy can yield comparable results to PhD training in the developed world. Scientific achievements may vary because of excellent training at good universities, but also because excellent students select (and are selected by) good universities. This paper compares the career effects of overseas and domestic PhD training for scholars working in an emerging economy, South Africa. We differentiate between and examine both selection and training effects for PhDs from three tiers of South African and two tiers of foreign universities. South African academics with PhDs from universities in industrialised countries generally achieve greater career success than those with local PhDs, but training by universities in industrialised countries is not necessarily better than local training. Our results suggest that the perceived superiority of foreign PhD training stems from selection rather than do training effects, and pure selection effects in fact explain career outcomes better than training effects. Focusing on training rather than selection, PhDs from top South African universities produce a similar quantity and quality research output to those trained by the leading universities in the developed world. From the perspective of an emerging economy with limited resources wishing to advance science, the development of local universities should thus be stressed, although it is clear that individuals who are able to study for a PhD abroad gain personally when they return.

    • This study explores the channels through which technological investments affect productivity performance of industrialized economies. Using a Stochastic Frontier Model (SFM) we estimate the productivity effects of R&D and ICT for a large sample of OECD industries between 1973 and 2007, identifying four channels of transmission: input accumulation, technological change, technical efficiency and spillovers. Our results show that ICT has been particularly effective in reducing production inefficiency and in generating inter-industry spillovers, while R&D has raised the rate of technical change and favoured knowledge spillovers within sectors. We also quantify the contribution of technological investments to output and total factor productivity growth documenting that R&D and ICT accounted for almost 95% of productivity growth in the OECD area.

    • This study empirically examines whether the research and development (R&D) activities of foreign-owned firms in Japan differ notably from the R&D activities of domestically-owned firms based on a firm-level panel dataset. Our study carefully disentangles the significant differences in R&D investment behavior of subsidiaries due to three different reasons: having a foreign parent, corporate group affiliation, and the degree of relatedness between business units. The results reveal the following. First, firms that are majority-owned by another firm are less active in R&D than independent firms. Second, foreign ownership does not matter if the parent firm is from a G7 country, but R&D intensity is significantly and positively associated with foreign ownership if the parent firm is from a non-G7 country. Finally, for subsidiaries whose business is related to that of their parent firm, the R&D intensity is lower if the parent is a domestic firm, but higher if it is a foreign firm. These findings imply that globalization and the integration of firms may not only affect production patterns and global supply chains, but may also have an important impact on the level of domestic R&D activities.

    • External collaboration breadth is important for firms to acquire the knowledge needed to innovate. In this paper, we combine cross-sectional and longitudinal data from the Spanish Panel of Technological Innovation Survey (PITEC) to examine the indirect impact of R&D subsidies on firm external collaboration breadth. We contribute to understanding of the indirect impacts of R&D subsidies by first providing strong evidence of an economically significant average positive impact of R&D subsidies on firm external collaboration breadth. Second, our results advance understanding of the differential impacts of R&D subsidies by revealing the vast heterogeneity of the impact at the firm level, where approximately only half of treated firms experience a positive collaboration impact from R&D subsidies, while the remainder experience no impact or a negative effect. Finally, we advance understanding of the characteristics explaining the differential impact of R&D subsidies on external collaboration breadth by utilising the organisational learning literature to demonstrate the important role of firm collaboration experience.

    • R&D consortia have been regarded as an effective means of promoting innovation. Several R&D consortia obtain public financial support, which may affect their governance structure and performance. This study investigates the governance mechanisms of publicly funded R&D consortia and their effects on innovation performance. Few studies have empirically addressed the effect of project monitoring by the government or the role of project leadership in R&D consortia. Focusing on a major support program for R&D consortia in Japan and using a sample of 251 firms that participated in publicly funded R&D consortia from 2004 to 2009, we empirically confirm that to enhance firms’ innovation performance, both project leadership as internal discipline and government monitoring as external discipline matter. Our results show that project leadership directly improves firms’ innovation performance, while firms’ commitment indirectly affects performance. Project leadership and government monitoring also promote commitment. Furthermore, both factors are complementary: consortia members are more willing to accept a project leader’s coordination under stricter government monitoring.

    • Innovative entrepreneurship is at the heart of economic development in all modern economic systems. However, we observe in several developed countries - especially Europe - a languishing in the capacity to foster creative destruction (i.e. Schumpeter Mark 1, SM1) dynamics and to create young innovative companies (YICs), capable to establish themselves as leaders in markets or become successful innovators. One key issue that is often advocated in this respect is the deficit suffered from YICs in fully protecting their innovations and appropriating (at least in part) returns from them. The usage of formal (e.g., intellectual property rights) and informal (e.g., secrecy, lead time, access to complementary assets) instruments to protect intellectual property assets has the potential to overcome this difficulty. Different types of policy mechanisms have been put in place to help YICs. However, high implicit and explicit costs and barriers prevent YICs’ use of protection strategies, limiting the ability to generate SM1 dynamics or accessing market for ideas, even upon policy support. By relying on the resource-based view of the firm, our paper investigates to what extent a comprehensive set of policy measures recently introduced in the Italian context and focused on alleviating the hurdles suffered by YICs is associated with the choice of YICs to protect their innovations. The econometric analyses based on more than 1,600 Italian YICs show how the use of financial policy measures are associated to both formal and informal instruments, while labour policy measures are only related to formal ones.

    View full text