Why was China unable to promote industrialization

You have 0 free articles left this month.

You are reading your last free article for this month.

Create an account to read 2 more.

In its attempts to industrialize, Africa has looked toward China’s success. China designed and executed a policy that shrank the industrialization process in a mere 25 years — something many economies took at least a century to do. That redesign has brought immense dislocation in global commerce and industry, enabling China to become one of the world’s leading economies. African leaders have been pursuing policies designed to mimic China’s path. But despite these efforts, Africa has yet to advance in its industrialization at the same speed China did. Put simply, the things that worked for China will not work for Africa. Africa must change its focus: It must encourage internal consumption and intra-trade, push forward the African Continental Free Trade Agreement, create a single African currency, improve infrastructure, and invest in education.

China designed and executed a policy that shrank the industrialization process in a mere 25 years — something that many economies took at least a century to do. That redesign has brought immense dislocation in global commerce and industry, enabling China to become one of the world’s leading economies.

China’s recent economic boom, although widely viewed as a contemporary phenomenon, is the outcome of long-term processes with deep historical roots.1 Here, we apply this perspective to analyse the trajectory that has transformed China from hesitant nineteenth-century experimentation into the world’s largest manufacturer.

Table 9.1 summarizes our central quantitative results. The unusual speed of China’s post-1978 industrial growth is well known. Much less appreciated is that rapid industrial growth extends back at least to 1912. Over a period spanning nearly a century, Chinese manufacturing has grown at an annual rate of more than 9 per cent. Table 9.2 provides further comparative perspective.

Table 9.1.

Comparative growth of industrial output, 1912–2008

ChinaJapanIndiaUSSR/Russia

1912–36

 

8.0

 

6.7

 

3.4

 

4.8

 

1912–49

 

4.1

 

2.5

 

3.9

 

3.9

 

1912–52

 

6.2

 

4.0

 

n.a.

 

4.8

 

1952–65

 

12.3

 

14.3

 

8.2

 

6.4

 

1965–78

 

10.2

 

8.2

 

4.3

 

3.8

 

1978–95

 

11.6

 

2.8

 

6.8

 

n.a.

 

1995–2008

 

13.8

 

0.7

 

7.8

 

3.1

 

1952–2008

 

11.9

 

6.1

 

6.8

 

n.a.

 

1912–2008

 

9.5

 

5.2

 

5.5

 

n.a.

 

Table 9.2.

Comparative industrialization: China, India, Japan, and Russia/USSR, 1912–2008

1912193319521965197819952008

Cotton yarn production (m. lbs)

 
       

China

 

221

 

990

 

1,445

 

2,860

 

5,240

 

11,928

 

38,214

 

India

 

647

 

1,268

 

1,452

 

2,068

 

2,006

 

3793

 

6,774

 

Japan

 

400

 

1,261

 

635

 

1,065

 

985

 

473

 

145

 

USSR/Russia

 
 

660

 
  

3,580

 

436

 
 

Electricity production (bn kWh)

 
       

China

 

0.1

 

2.8

 

7.3

 

67.6

 

256.6

 

1,007.0

 

3,496.0

 

India

 
 

2.1

 

6.1

 

31.4

 

110.1

 

396.0

 

841.7

 

Japan

 

1.1

 

19.5

 

52.0

 

179.6

 

564.0

 

990.0

 

1,146.0

 

USSR/Russia

 

2.0

 

16.4

 

119.1

 

506.7

 

1,293.9

 

860.0

 

983.0

 

Ingot steel production (m. tonnes)

 
       

China

 

0.0

 

0.4

 

1.4

 

12.2

 

31.8

 

95.4

 

503.0

 

India

 

0.0

 

0.5

 

1.6

 

6.4

 

9.9

 

22.0

 

57.8

 

Japan

 

0.0

 

3.2

 

7.0

 

39.8

 

102.1

 

101.6

 

118.7

 

USSR/Russia

 

4.2

 

8.9

 

34.5

 

91.0

 

151.5

 

51.6

 

68.5

 

Cement production (m. tonnes)

 
       

China

 

0.1

 

0.8

 

2.9

 

16.3

 

65.2

 

475.6

 

1,423.6

 

India

 

0.0

 

1.1

 

4.6

 

10.6

 

19.4

 

74.0

 

177.0

 

Japan

 

0.3

 

4.2

 

8.9

 

32.5

 

84.9

 

90.5

 

62.8

 

USSR/Russia

 

1.6

 

2.7

 

13.9

 

72.4

 

127.0

 

36.4

 

53.6

 

Industrial employment (m.)

 
       

Chinaa

 

0.7

 

1.1

 

5.3

 

16.6

 

53.3

 

147.4

 

126.3

 

India (formal only)

 

0.9

 

1.5

 

3.2

 

4.7

 

5.4

 
 

5.9

 

Indiaa (formal + informal)

 
     

37.3

 

46.0

 

Japan

 

1.6

 

4.2

 

7.2

 

11.5

 

13.3

 

14.6

 

8.3

 

USSR/Russia

 

2.3

 

6.2–9.3

 

16.8

 

27.4

 

29.0

 
  

China’s experience demonstrates, however, that industrialization is not simply the multiplication of commodity flows in and out of furnaces, mills, and machine shops. How growth occurs, the relative roles of the intensive and extensive margins, and more generally, the underlying microeconomic processes are key to maintaining long-run momentum, and to industrialization’s economy-wide impact. Similar growth rates of manufacturing can conceal wide differences in the progress of industrialization, which we see as a fundamentally microeconomic process that enables firms and individuals to accumulate and deepen the technical, operational, managerial, and commercial skills that enable them to compete in ever more demanding markets, releasing multiple benefit streams that then reverberate throughout the economy. China’s planned economy period, covering roughly 1952–78, recorded impressive rates of output growth, but did so under a policy and institutional environment that ultimately restricted the pace of change to a fraction of its potential, and carried high costs for the rest of the economy. Institutional and policy constraints similarly obstructed early industrialization efforts in the late nineteenth century.

Two factors have consistently served as important drivers of Chinese industry’s global rise: openness to the international economy and domestic market liberalization.

Openness is important for the access it allows to new technology and know-how through foreign direct investment (FDI), imports of intermediates and capital equipment, and the movement of people and ideas. For a huge continental economy like China’s in which the domestic market has typically absorbed upwards of 85 per cent of industrial output (Table 9.3), openness defined solely in terms of access to overseas markets cannot claim paramount importance. Domestic market liberalization is the crucial source of new opportunities and competitive pressure on incumbents and entrants to upgrade through product improvement and cost reductions, thus channelling resources to firms and sectors with high returns.

Table 9.3.

Chinese exports of manufactures: scale and share of production and overall exports, 1933–2008

Unit193319521965197819952008

Total exports

 

RMB bn

 

0.898a

 

2.71

 

6.31

 

16.76

 

1,245.18

 

10,039.49

 

of which: Manufactures

 

RMB bn

 

0.247a

 

0.41

 

2.84

 

9.22

 

1,065.24

 

9,492.50

 

Share of manufactures in exports

 

per cent

 

27.5

 

15.0

 

45.0

 

55.0

 

85.5

 

94.6

 

GVIO, current prices

 

RMB bn

 
 

34.9

 

140.2

 

423.7

 

9,189.4

 

60,737.92243

 

Manufacturing share in GVIO

 

per cent

 

83.4

 

88

 

88

 

88

 

88

 

88

 

GVIO manufacturing

 

RMB bn

 

2.645a

 

30.7

 

123.4

 

372.9

 

8,086.7

 

53,449.4

 

Share of manufacturing output exported

 

per cent

 

9.3

 

1.3

 

2.3

 

2.5

 

13.2

 

17.8

 

Trade ratio [X + M]/GDP

 

per cent

 

8.8

 

9.6

 

6.9

 

11.8

 

38.7

 

57.3

 

For latecomers like China, modern industry initially involves labour-intensive production requiring only modest capabilities. Over time, upgrading propels a shift into more skilled-labour and capital-intensive products and processes. Our review of a century and a half of Chinese industrialization shows that upgrading occurred most rapidly when the policy environment provided ample opportunity for the complementary interaction between openness and market liberalization, and helped roll back the institutional barriers that have often hindered the deepening of industrial capabilities.

While the past 150 years have seen wide variations in both international openness and domestic liberalization, we can identify several major dimensions of industrial development that have operated continuously throughout the period under review, albeit at different levels of intensity.

First, manufacturing activity and industrial capabilities have gradually spread across China’s vast landscape. Factory production initially clustered along China’s southeastern coast, particularly in the Lower Yangzi region surrounding Shanghai, and subsequently in Manchuria. The war years (1937–49) brought a surprisingly large expansion of industry in China’s interior (Table 9.4). The planned economy era (1949–78) modestly extended regional dispersion, most notably through the Third Front policies, as the state limited investment in previously dominant regions, which were seen as both militarily vulnerable and ideologically suspect, and developed industrial capacity inland. Although the post-1978 reform era allowed coastal regions once again to leverage their favourable location and superior resources of education, skill, and market experience to regain their share of national production, nationwide infrastructure expansion along with steeply rising land and labour costs in coastal cities encouraged growth in the central and western regions.

Table 9.4.

Share of industrial output by region, 1933–2008

Region193319521965197819952008

NE

 

11.8

 

21.6

 

21.0

 

17.1

 

9.7

 

7.4

 

North

 

13.6

 

20.8

 

21.4

 

23.0

 

20.4

 

24.2

 

SE Coast

 

65.7

 

36.6

 

32.8

 

30.0

 

40.7

 

45.8

 

Central

 

7.9

 

11.0

 

12.3

 

15.0

 

16.0

 

12.9

 

NW

 

0.0

 

2.5

 

4.9

 

5.6

 

3.7

 

2.7

 

SW

 

0.9

 

7.5

 

7.6

 

9.3

 

9.6

 

7.0

 

Total

 

100.0

 

100.0

 

100.0

 

100.0

 

100.0

 

100.0

 

Herfindahl index

 

0.23

 

0.09

 

0.07

 

0.06

 

0.06

 

0.08

 

Regions:

 
      

NE

 

Heilongjiang

 

Jilin

 

Liaoning

 
   

North

 

Beijing

 

Tianjin

 

Inner Mongolia

 

Shanxi

 

Hebei

 

Shandong

 

SE Coast

 

Jiangsu

 

Shanghai

 

Zhejiang

 

Fujian

 

Guangdong

 

Hainan

 

Central

 

Henan

 

Anhui

 

Hubei

 

Hunan

 

Jiangxi

 
 

NW

 

Shaanxi

 

Ningxia

 

Gansu

 

Qinghai

 

Xinjiang

 
 

SW

 

Sichuan

 

Chongqing

 

Guangxi

 

Yunnan

 

Guizhou

 

Xizang

 

Second, the industrial product mix has expanded. Even without tariff protection, import substitution is visible from the late nineteenth century, particularly in cotton textiles. Import replacement on a more modest scale appeared elsewhere, particularly in segments of machine building, where the 1930s saw Chinese firms producing small quantities of textile machinery, machine tools, transportation equipment, and light armaments. Socialist planning grafted whole sectors, including trucks, petroleum refining, telecom equipment, nuclear fuel, and many others, onto the inherited industrial base. Although reform allowed market forces to exert growing influence over China’s industrial product mix, government agencies continued to promote import replacement in computers, chemicals, machine tools, and other sectors that officials perceived as either essential building blocks for future development or militarily important.

Third, domestic upgrading has reduced the gap separating leading Chinese producers from global standards. Even without strong official support, progress in this direction became visible during the 1920s and 1930s, especially in cotton textiles. Chinese yarn producers moved beyond the coarsest grades of cotton yarn, improved labour and machine productivity, and absorbed management practices from British and Japanese rivals, while new academies offered training programmes in textile technology and civic organizations hired foreign technicians to facilitate the production and dissemination of Japanese-style equipment for handcraft weaving.

Beginning in the 1950s, the government of the People’s Republic (PRC), tapping its new fiscal strength and the availability of technical support from its Soviet and East European allies, initiated what was then the largest technology transfer in human history. While the characteristic Soviet focus on production volume limited quality improvements and innovation, the accumulation of knowledge, resources, and experience under the planned economy created upgrading potential that could be captured once post-1978 reforms encouraged the revival of incentives and allowed greater flexibility in the allocation of resources.

Upgrading accelerated after 1978, spurred by the growing presence of foreign-invested firms, the unfamiliar demands of new export markets in rich countries, and the opportunities arising from growing access to international supply chains and cross-national information flows. The result was a growing dispersion of capabilities, as successful firms gradually moved toward global frontiers, leaving weaker units floundering in often overcrowded domestic markets for inferior goods.

Fourth, despite wrenching political discontinuity, successive advances built on prior developments. Early industrial efforts often involved individuals with modern education and/or overseas experience—both linked to international openness. Personnel from the pre-1949 National Resources Commission and from Japanese-controlled development efforts in Manchuria contributed disproportionately to early socialist planning. Even though the planned economy diverted investment away from Shanghai, China’s pre-war industrial leader, the great metropolis figured centrally in the new system as a source of revenue from the profits of its consumer manufactures, and as a source of expert personnel—especially in textiles. Interior development was seeded with whole factory communities transported from Shanghai and other coastal locations. Reform-era development drew in similar fashion on the experience and skills accumulated within the plan-era state enterprise system, which became a source of expertise for both the township-village (TVE) firms and emerging private sector manufacturers (Li, Bathelt, and Wang, 2012; Dinh et al., 2013).

Finally, the Chinese diaspora has acted as a substantial source of financial and human capital in all periods except for the planned economy era. Its prominence reflects the unusual entrepreneurial propensity of ordinary Chinese, which survived several decades of intense anti-business propaganda under Mao and emerged as a key element in the astonishing reform-era expansion of private business (Table 9.5). Large numbers of micro-entrepreneurs in Wenzhou and other localities helped to propel Chinese exports to dominant positions in global market segments—an unusual, perhaps unique, phenomenon in global economic history.

Table 9.5.

Breakdown of industrial output by ownership, 1933–2008 (per cent)

Foreign firm sharesDomestic firm sharesPer cent ofdomestic non-stateSector19331985199520081933198519952008198519952008

Metallurgy

 

3.3

 

0.0

 

3.4

 

8.0

 

96.7

 

100.0

 

96.6

 

92.0

 

32.4

 

25.6

 

40.3

 

Power

 

100.0

 

0.0

 

5.1

 

4.6

 
 

100.0

 

94.9

 

95.4

 

8.0

 

13.8

 

6.5

 

Coal and coke

 

0.0

 

0.0

 

0.1

 

1.5

 

100.0

 

100.0

 

99.9

 

98.5

 

18.6

 

22.2

 

21.1

 

Petroleum

 

100.0

 

0.0

 

4.1

 

4.5

 
 

100.0

 

95.9

 

95.5

 

5.5

 

3.7

 

13.9

 

Chemicals

 

22.7

 

0.1

 

8.5

 

17.2

 

77.3

 

99.9

 

91.5

 

82.8

 

37.9

 

41.6

 

52.8

 

Machinery

 

20.6

 

0.6

 

15.7

 

35.0

 

79.4

 

99.4

 

84.3

 

65.0

 

28.4

 

43.9

 

55.7

 

Building materials

 

3.8

 

0.0

 

4.9

 

7.2

 

96.2

 

100.0

 

95.1

 

92.8

 

57.5

 

69.9

 

70.1

 

Timber

 

52.1

 

0.0

 

10.4

 

10.3

 

47.9

 

100.0

 

89.6

 

89.7

 

46.5

 

78.2

 

84.3

 

Food and drink

 

20.9

 

0.2

 

5.7

 

17.9

 

79.1

 

99.8

 

94.3

 

82.1

 

14.6

 

28.0

 

52.0

 

Textiles

 

25.6

 

0.1

 

13.7

 

10.8

 

74.4

 

99.9

 

86.3

 

89.2

 

33.6

 

76.1

 

74.3

 

Paper

 

13.0

 

0.1

 

5.8

 

15.3

 

87.0

 

99.9

 

94.2

 

84.7

 

62.7

 

47.0

 

70.5

 

Total

 

21.9

 

0.2

 

9.8

 

23.3

 

78.1

 

99.8

 

90.2

 

76.7

 

30.1

 

41.6

 

52.7

 

Following a brief quantitative overview, we review development during three periods: the decades prior to the establishment of the PRC in 1949; China’s era of socialist planning, which extends from the early 1950s to the late 1970s; and the succeeding period of economic reform, which begins shortly after the death of Mao Zedong (1976) and continues today.

Table 9.1 provides a comparative perspective on China’s long-term industrial growth ending with 2008, the most recent census year for which firm-level data are publicly available.2 With the sole exception of Japan during its heyday of accelerated growth, the pace of Chinese industrial expansion exceeded that of India, Japan, and USSR/Russia during every sub-period for which meaningful comparison is feasible. Table 9.2 uses information on physical commodity output and industrial employment to provide crude comparisons of the scale of industrial activity in China, India, Japan, and USSR/Russia during the century beginning in 1912. These data portray early-twentieth-century China as an industrial pygmy, trailing India’s production of cotton textiles and lagging far behind Japanese and Russian/Soviet production of electricity, steel, and cement.

Data for 1933 and 1952 suggest rough parity between Chinese and Indian industrial activity. An international comparison of industrial energy use during 1936/7 provides a clear ranking: industries in China (including Manchuria) and British India each absorb the equivalent of 19 billion kWh of electricity per year, one-third of the figure for Japan and one-sixth of the total for the USSR (US Department of State, 1949, pp. 96–7).

Manufacturing contributed 2.1 and 3.2 per cent of China’s 1933 and 1952 GDP respectively (in 1933 prices); adding mining and utilities (but not handicrafts) raises the 1933 figure to 3.3 per cent (Liu and Yeh, 1965, p. 66). PRC compilations show a rapid increase in the GDP share of industry (including mining and utilities), which rises to 44.1, 41.0, and 48.6 per cent in 1978, 1995, and 2008 (Compendium, 2009, p. 10).

Beginning in the mid-1950s, Chinese industry rapidly outpaced India’s. China’s scale of industrial operations overtook Japan’s shortly before the turn of the century, and surpassed the USSR’s peak levels soon after 2000.

We observe three phases of pre-1949 industrialization: slow development during the late nineteenth century, including both officially inspired and private commercial efforts, followed by a more dynamic, market-driven expansion triggered by the Treaty of Shimonoseki (1895), which eroded barriers to private factory ventures. Subsequently, Japanese military pressure culminating in the Sino-Japanese War (1937–45) and civil war (1945–9) prompted growing state intervention. Over this period, government became the chief driver of industrial development, leading to a rise in the share of military-linked activity and an enlarged output share for interior regions.

The Treaty of Nanking, which ended the Opium War (1839–42), obliged China to open five ports to unlimited trade, to limit tariffs to 5 per cent, and to exempt foreigners from Chinese law. Later agreements multiplied the number of ‘treaty ports’ and awarded similar privileges to citizens of multiple European nations as well as the United States and Japan. The resulting regime of obligatory free trade lasted until China regained tariff autonomy in 1929.

Falling international transport and communication costs complemented by rising trade volumes gradually aligned China’s price structure, which displayed substantial domestic integration before the Opium War (Wang, 1992), with global values (Brandt, 1985). The resulting changes included price reductions (cotton yarn, ferrous metals) and increases (cotton, silk, tea), as well as the appearance of new products (machinery, kerosene, matches) that impacted prices of domestic substitutes and complements for traded goods.

Openness elicited a strong response in some segments of China’s economy, such as Fujian’s tea growers (Gardella, 1994, pp. 74ff). Development of manufacturing, however, was slow, both for semi-official initiatives directed by prominent regional leaders and for private ventures, some involving foreign entrepreneurs, that focused on processing of silk and other farm products. While the Jiangnan Arsenal impressed Japanese visitors, and China’s Hanyeping complex initiated modern ferrous metallurgy ahead of Japan’s Yahata works, the officially linked initiatives, most focused on defence-related production, delivered limited results and produced virtually no spillovers for the private sector.

An earlier literature mistakenly linked this slow growth to the supposed inability of modern factory goods to compete with the products of China’s traditional sector (Murphey, 1977; Huang, 1985). In reality, modern technologies enabled factory products to outcompete many traditional products in price and quality. Given Japan’s faster industrial advance under similar trade and treaty arrangements, attributing limited manufacturing growth to Western imperialism is equally unpersuasive (Esherick, 1972; Moulder, 1977).

Institutional and ideological constraints that drained potential profits from embryonic industrial ventures posed a key obstacle to modern industry. Shannon Brown (1978, 1979a, 1979 b) and others demonstrate how these difficulties undermined initiatives in soybean and silk processing. Entrenched local interest groups, possibly strengthened under the decentralization that accompanied the Taiping Rebellion (Brandt, Ma, and Rawski, 2014), thwarted potential competition by blocking newcomers’ access to materials (soybeans, cocoons), storage facilities, and transport.

In addition to opening the growing roster of treaty ports to foreign-owned manufacturing activity, the stunning military defeat at the hands of Japan, a small and lightly regarded neighbour, prompted a sweeping reconsideration of traditional attitudes and structures. Rapid retreat of formal and, perhaps more important, informal restrictions and prejudices became the order of the day as even conservative leaders endorsed sweeping reform. A new company law introduced limited liability; the traditional examination system gave way to a new drive toward modern education; Confucian-educated gentry turned to constitutionalism, parliamentary democracy, and chambers of commerce as possible avenues to reverse China’s decline.

This ferment facilitated a rapid acceleration of industrial enterprise formation. Table 9.6 shows the number of newly established modern Chinese private factories more than doubling between the 1880s and 1890s from 42 to 99, before increasing to 437 during the first decade of the twentieth century. This wave of entry, complemented by growing FDI (Remer, 1933; Hou, 1965) initiated several decades of rapid industrial growth that persisted through periods of disunity, war, and depression. Halting only with the outbreak of full-scale war with Japan in 1937, pre-war industrial growth outstripped that in Japan as well as India and Russia/USSR (Table 9.1). Work by Chinese scholars finds similarly high growth for Shanghai—the centre of pre-war manufacturing—between 1895 and 1912 (Ma, 2008).

Table 9.6.

Number of domestic, privately owned modern factories established, by region and decade, 1841–1915

Region1841–501851–601861–701871–801881–901891–19001901–101911–15Pre-1911 totalPre-1911 share

NE

 
    

1

 

6

 

47

 

47

 

54

 

9.1

 

North

 
   

1

 

3

 

11

 

77

 

90

 

92

 

15.6

 

SE Coast

 

1

 

4

 

3

 

3

 

37

 

69

 

203

 

209

 

320

 

54.1

 

Central

 
   

1

 
 

11

 

66

 

38

 

78

 

13.2

 

NW

 
      

1

 

5

 

1

 

0.2

 

SW

 
    

1

 

2

 

43

 

49

 

46

 

7.8

 

Total

 

1

 

4

 

3

 

5

 

42

 

99

 

437

 

438

 

591

 

100.0

 

Rapid growth from a minuscule base could not transform China into an industrial nation. At its pre-war 1936 peak, factory output accounted for only 3.1 per cent of GDP—far below the comparable Japanese figure of 25.1 per cent. Even with a substantial downward adjustment to the Liu-Yeh estimates of 1933 production,3 handicrafts contributed nearly half of industry gross output (and value added) in 1933, comparable to Japanese circumstances during 1900–10 (Ohkawa and Shinohara, 1979, p. 37).

Labour-intensive production of consumer goods dominated China’s early industrial landscape. Textiles, garments, and food processing accounted for two-thirds of 1933 industrial output with or without the inclusion of handicrafts (Table 9.7).

Table 9.7.

Breakdown of industrial output by sector

YearCoverageMetallurgyPowerCoal and cokePetroleumChemicalsMachineryBuilding materialsTimberFood and drinkTextilesPaper

1933

 

Total

 

1.9

 

0.9

 

4.4

 

0.5

 

1.4

 

5.2

 

1.8

 

5.4

 

30.9

 

42.4

 

5.0

 
 

Modern only

 

3.8

 

1.8

 

8.5

 

1.0

 

1.9

 

5.7

 

1.2

 

0.8

 

30.0

 

43.4

 

1.9

 

1952

 

Total

 

5.4

 

1.4

 

4.6

 

0.6

 

1.9

 

6.2

 

2.8

 

9.2

 

31.4

 

34.5

 

2.2

 

1965

 

Total

 

13.0

 

3.5

 

4.8

 

3.6

 

7.3

 

16.0

 

3.2

 

4.6

 

20.0

 

21.6

 

2.3

 

1978

 

Total

 

10.3

 

4.1

 

3.8

 

6.8

 

12.1

 

25.7

 

4.2

 

2.4

 

12.9

 

16.3

 

1.5

 

1995

 

Total

 

8.7

 

3.6

 

1.6

 

2.4

 

15.0

 

29.9

 

6.9

 

1.5

 

11.6

 

15.9

 

2.6

 

2008

 

Total

 

8.1

 

3.5

 

0.8

 

0.8

 

12.7

 

49.1

 

4.1

 

1.4

 

7.4

 

10.0

 

2.0

 

Industrial activity was regionally concentrated. Nearly two-thirds of 1933 industrial production was located in the southeast coastal provinces (Table 9.4), with half more narrowly clustered in Shanghai and the adjacent Jiangsu province. A further 10 per cent was located in China’s northeast (Manchurian) region, largely tied to Japanese investments. Data on newly established private factories prior to 1911 (Table 9.6) show a similar pattern of regional clustering.

Extreme geographic concentration resulted in large variations in industry’s GDP share. For Shanghai and the adjacent Lower Yangzi region, an area with a population of 60 million, the GDP share of modern industry during the early 1930s may have reached 15 per cent, three times the national total and comparable to the role of industry in Japan by the late 1920s.4 Vast regions, especially in the west, experienced very limited development of modern industry prior to 1937.

Domestic entrepreneurs succeeded in rapidly overcoming their initial disadvantages—inferior technical knowledge, poorer financing, and treaty provisions exempting foreign firms from many Chinese taxes. Table 9.8, which decomposes 1933 factory activity in China proper,5 puts the share of Chinese-owned firms in output and employment at 78 and 83 per cent respectively.6

Table 9.8.

Gross output value and employment in manufacturing by type of firm, China proper, 1933

Gross output valueEmploymentChinese firmsForeign firmsChinese firmsForeign firmsChinese firmsForeign firmsChinese firmsForeign firmsMillion yuanShareThousandsShare

Metallurgy

 

83

 

2.8

 

96.7

 

3.3

 

20.1

 

0.9

 

95.7

 

4.3

 

Power

 
        

Coal and coke

 

0.5

 
 

100.0

 

0.0

 

0.2

 
 

100.0

 

0.0

 

Petroleum

 
        

Chemicals

 

86.7

 

25.5

 

77.3

 

22.7

 

42.3

 

8.9

 

82.6

 

17.4

 

Machinery

 

68.8

 

17.9

 

79.4

 

20.6

 

52.2

 

8.2

 

86.4

 

13.6

 

Building materials

 

45.8

 

1.8

 

96.2

 

3.8

 

36

 

1.1

 

97.0

 

3.0

 

Timber

 

5.6

 

6.1

 

47.9

 

52.1

 

1.7

 

1.7

 

50.0

 

50.0

 

Food and drink

 

597.8

 

158.1

 

79.1

 

20.9

 

72.8

 

28.3

 

72.0

 

28.0

 

Textiles

 

793.6

 

272.7

 

74.4

 

25.6

 

505.6

 

108.3

 

82.4

 

17.6

 

Paper

 

74.9

 

11.2

 

87.0

 

13.0

 

43.8

 

3.8

 

92.0

 

8.0

 

Other

 

13.8

 

1.5

 

90.2

 

9.8

 

7.9

 

1.4

 

84.9

 

15.1

 

Total

 

1,770.5

 

497.6

 

78.1

 

21.9

 

782.6

 

162.6

 

82.8

 

17.2

 

Even though 90 per cent of 1933 factory production was sold domestically (Table 9.3), global market forces powerfully affected Chinese manufacturing throughout the pre-war period. New domestic producers usually faced the task of wresting market share from foreign manufactures, which attracted domestic buyers by offering alternatives for traditional products (manufactured yarn substituting for handicraft, cigarettes replacing pipe tobacco, kerosene being used for lighting rather than vegetable oil) and ‘new’ goods (matches, steam engines). As a result, China’s pre-war factory output closely paralleled the economy’s comparative advantage.

Cotton textiles, pre-war China’s leading industry, illustrate this tight link between global markets and pre-war factory development. Imports of manufactured yarn and cloth established market niches that were subsequently captured by local producers. Imports of yarn declined steeply after peaking in 1903 and again in 1914, and China emerged as a net exporter of cotton yarn beginning in 1927. Fabric imports peaked in 1913; by 1932–6, their share in domestic consumption had dropped from over 25 per cent during 1901–10 to only 8 per cent (Hsiao, 1974, pp. 38–9, 86; Kraus, 1980, pp. 116, J-3; Feuerwerker, 1970; Brandt, 1989).

International influence permeated the development process. Chinese textile entrepreneurs hired foreign-trained technical staff, purchased imported equipment with advice from Shanghai-based foreign specialists, dispatched their sons to study abroad, and borrowed from foreign banks.

Competition among imports and domestic goods from foreign- and Chinese-owned factories spawned market segmentation, with Chinese firms initially serving the lower price/quality segments of contested product markets (Sutton, 2012). Chinese textile entrepreneurs initially produced yarn rather than fabric, and concentrated on low-count varieties, leaving the finer grades to foreign rivals (Hou, 1965, p. 153).

Market evolution and competitive pressure pushed firms to upgrade. During the 1920s, access to Japanese machinery and shifts in local demand encouraged spinning firms to shift their focus from ‘coarse low count yarn to…fine, high-quality, high-count’ varieties (Köll, 2003, p. 265). Forcing out independent shop bosses and installing technically trained managers enabled some firms to secure steep productivity increases (Cochran, 2000, pp. 191ff; Zeitz, 2013). Chinese yarn producers matched the rising productivity of China-based Japanese firms and outperformed British-owned rivals during 1924–36; in factory weaving, incomplete data show Chinese firms raising output per loom from 59 to 84 per cent of the levels recorded by Japanese-owned industry leaders (Zeitz, 2013, p. 125; Chao, 1977, p. 313).

Matches present a similar picture, with imports giving way to domestic production first by foreign and then by Chinese-owned firms. Liu Hongsheng, China’s ‘match king’, built his business in small cities ignored by foreign rivals, where customers put a premium on price over quality, and only later challenged the Japanese and Swedes in the Shanghai market, China’s largest (Cochran, 1992, p. 61). Liu’s strategy foreshadows the recent success of PRC start-ups in telecom equipment (Huawei) and construction machinery (Sany, Zoomlion, Liugong) that used capabilities accumulated through selling lower-quality goods to less demanding markets to break into high-end global markets that were initially dominated by prominent multinationals like Caterpillar and Ericsson (Brandt and Thun, 2010).

Estimating the scale and growth of handicrafts is difficult, but several propositions are clear.

Enforced free trade and factory expansion disrupted some craft sectors while giving new life to others. The overall effect was probably beneficial: exports of selected handicrafts grew at an average rate of 2.6 per cent per annum during 1875–1928, while combined exports of sixty-seven handicrafts rose by an average of 1.1 per cent annually during 1912–31 (Hou, 1965, p. 171).

Cotton textiles illustrate this mixed outcome. Handicraft spinning, squeezed by the dual blows of falling prices for factory yarn and rising cotton prices, suffered a steep decline (Feuerwerker, 1970). But the same low prices of factory yarn strengthened handicraft weaving, which thrived by combining factory and homespun yarns (Reynolds, 1974). Grove (2006) describes the critical role of Japanese advice and Japanese intermediate technology (wooden handlooms with iron gears) in expanding small-scale cloth production in north China.

Despite rapid factory growth, handicrafts persisted as an important component of industrial output as late as 1955, when they accounted for nearly 20 per cent of overall industrial production (Chen, 1967, p. 210).

Japan’s 1931 takeover of China’s northeast region, followed by a brief but intense attack on Shanghai in early 1932, focused attention on the need to prepare for war with Japan. The response included the establishment of official planning bodies, efforts to develop a network of state enterprises in defence-related industries, and monetary and banking reforms aimed at strengthening official control over money and credit. With the Japanese-led breakaway state of Manshūkoku adopting its own planned economy regimen, the approach of war initiated a nationwide shift from private to public enterprise and from market to government allocation that presaged the socialist system of the 1950s.

Once full-scale combat began in 1937, the combined effects of physical destruction, disruption of commercial and transport networks, fiscal difficulties arising from the westward retreat of China’s national government, and hyperinflation undermined private manufacturing and limited the implementation of industrialization plans, especially for Chiang Kai-shek’s Nationalist government. Consumer manufacturing centred on Shanghai suffered catastrophic reductions in capacity utilization: operating rates in flour milling fell by nearly 90 per cent between 1936 and 1945; in textiles, the decline was even steeper (Minami and Makino, 2014, Annex Table 4.D).

Official industrialization efforts, however, moved forward despite the travails of war. Indeed, rapid manufacturing growth immediately following the cessation of civil war in 1949 reflects substantial wartime increases in manufacturing capacity—expansion that pushed 1952 output to double the 1933 level and 65 per cent above the 1936 figure. Wartime investments also altered China’s industrial structure, raising the share of producer goods from 25 to 42 per cent of manufacturing output, increasing the share of central, southwest and northwestern regions from 8.8 to 21 per cent, and sharply reducing the Herfindahl index for provincial industrial output from 0.25 to 0.09 between 1933 and 1952 (Table 9.4).

A century after British arms imposed a regimen of free trade, China in 1949 remained a primarily agricultural economy. Although industry grew rapidly during the early decades of the twentieth century, the share of manufacturing in overall output remained small. Even so, China recorded substantial progress along the path to industrialization. Following several decades of slow expansion, the shock of military defeat and the 1895 treaty provisions allowing foreign-owned factories in China’s treaty ports unleashed a wave of reform. The ensuing acceleration of entry and growth provided China with a modest array of manufacturing industries, some of which—notably cotton textiles—achieved global visibility, that employed over 1 million workers in 1933 (Liu and Yeh, 1965, p. 428).

China’s leading industrial regions, the Shanghai area and the northeast, reflected divergent sources of growth. In the Lower Yangzi region centred on Shanghai, private business was the main driver of pre-war industrial growth. Beginning around 1900, rapid expansion of consumer goods manufacturing powered an economy-wide transformation that paralleled Japan’s earlier path. Expanding production of cotton goods, foodstuffs, matches, and other consumer goods promoted backward linkage into engineering and chemicals, stimulated the development of commodity and financial exchanges, and prompted banks to extend financing to manufacturing and even agriculture (Rawski, 1980, 1989; Ma, 2008). Prior to 1931, government involvement was mostly indirect; support of modern banks, ‘the sector…that benefited most from its dealings with the government’, was particularly significant (Kirby, 1984, p. 80). This changed after 1931 as the threat, and then the reality, of war with Japan pushed the Chinese state to assert growing control over industries and markets previously influenced mainly by private activity, and to inject itself directly into the allocation and operation of industrial resources.

In Manchuria, by contrast, government direction was evident throughout, with much factory investment coming from Japanese-controlled companies whose actions responded to Tokyo’s economic priorities. Reflecting this circumstance, chemicals, machinery, and, from 1936, metals—the central components of detailed official plans that extended into the 1950s—stand out as the largest contributors to factory value added (Chao, 1982, p. 83).

These developments occurred in an open economy, with free trade (from 1842), substantial price integration with global markets (from the 1880s), minimal restriction of FDI (from 1895), rapid expansion of new forms of education and overseas study, and considerable return migration by overseas Chinese. Extensive openness magnified both the disruption (e.g. to handicraft spinning) and the opportunities resulting from the growth of international links.

Gradual emergence of growth-promoting institutions contributed to China’s pre-war industrial growth. Private actors banded together to promote common interests. Köll (2003, p. 76) describes the spread of technical schools offering courses in textile engineering, the proliferation of technical journals and the emergence of an engineering profession, all foreshadowing developments that were vastly accelerated under state auspices after 1949. Local chambers of commerce facilitated the dissemination of know-how and provided ‘voice’ for newly emerging entrepreneurs (Chan, 1977).

State action, initially focused on sponsorship of semi-official enterprises during the late ninteenth century, subsequently emphasized indirect actions that smoothed the path of private ventures: passing a corporation law, identifying and disseminating commercially promising technologies, and pursuing tariff autonomy.

As a result, China’s pre-war economy displayed many features of a market system. Prices were flexible and generally market-determined. There were few man-made obstacles to domestic or international mobility of goods, people, information, and ideas. Formal and informal entry barriers declined over time. Low revenue and, after 1911, weak central control restricted the state’s ability to regulate and intervene.

This began to change soon after the Guomindang established the Nanjing government in 1927. Although restricted by weak finances and limited territorial control, the new administration set out to follow Japan and other rising powers by systematically deploying the levers of state power to build a modern industrial economy. Japan’s assault on China’s territorial integrity, which signalled a growing likelihood of all-out war, hastened the Guomindang’s shift from supporting a largely private economy toward an emerging vision of a planned economy in which official direction of investment and state-owned enterprises (SOEs) would occupy leading roles.

The outbreak of war in 1937 led to ‘an enormous expansion of Nationalist China’s economic bureaucracy’, nationalization of many existing industrial operations, and planned production and distribution of essential war materials (Kirby, 1990, pp. 127–8). By 1944, public sector firms accounted for more than half of total industrial output and an even higher share of heavy industry (Bian, 2002, p. 85).

While the defeat of Japan brought a renewal of China’s long-smouldering civil strife, the Guomindang and Communists shared a common vision of an industrial sector oriented toward military strength, directed by government technocrats, and dominated by state-run firms. When Communist forces routed their Guomindang rivals, ‘the large majority of Nationalist industrial planning personnel’, including the ‘entire senior leadership’ of the National Resources Council, the KMT’s lead agency for economic planning, ‘remained on the mainland’, imparting a strong element of continuity to the establishment of Soviet-aided socialist planning by the incoming PRC government (Kirby, 1990, p. 134).

The Chinese economy recovered quickly with the end of hostilities and the establishment of the PRC in 1949. By the mid-1950s, China had succeeded in further institutionalizing and extending the system inherited from the preceding wartime era. In industry, two features were especially prominent: state ownership and the substitution of a planning system for markets.

Industry under socialism is as much a story of continuity as it is of change. State ownership had come to the fore during the 1940s. Nationalization of remaining private firms in the early 1950s and the concentration of new investment in the state sector simply reinforced this dominance. Between 1957 and 1978, the state sector consistently delivered over 80 per cent of gross value of industrial output (GVIO), with the remainder coming from a large number of small urban collective firms and, beginning in the late 1950s, from an even larger number of rural collective enterprises.

Through an enlarged and integrated version of separate planning bureaucracies inherited from the former Guomindang and Manshūkoku governments, China moved to fully replace markets with administrative resource allocation. Decisions about output, input use, and investment were now all in the hands of the planners.

Although China’s plan system resembled its Soviet counterpart, there were important differences. The number of commodities for which planners constructed nationwide allocations was smaller than in the USSR. China’s system was more decentralized, with substantial resources under the control of provincial and sub-provincial governments (Wong, 1985). This decentralization reflected a succession of initiatives that began during the mid-1950s and continued through the next two decades. Maskin, Qian, and Xu (2000) argue that this feature of the pre-1978 economy had important consequences for the system’s reform-era trajectory.

A central objective of the new system was to mobilize resources that planners could direct toward strategic objectives. Control over prices was critical: by setting prices of final goods high relative to those for inputs, including wages, planners could concentrate profits in the hands of SOEs. Low profit retention rates—firms were required to remit more than 95 per cent of their profits—provided a revenue stream for the state that accounted for a large share of fiscal receipts.7

Security concerns and the desire to narrow the gap with the West put a high premium on investment and the expansion in China’s producer goods sector, such as steel, machine tools, and chemicals. As in the USSR, and in sharp contrast to the first three decades of the twentieth century, Chinese planning pursued industrial development without reference to comparative advantage. Moreover, with the notable exception of the sizable inflows of equipment, technology, and expertise from the Soviet bloc during the 1950s, Chinese leaders limited the country’s ties to global markets. International isolation, which reflected a combination of ideological conviction and the impact of a US-led trade embargo, pushed China’s trade ratio far below the levels attained during the 1930s (Table 9.3).

These institutional arrangements delivered three decades of rapid industrial expansion, surpassing earlier rates of growth. After doubling between 1949 and 1952 with the revival of the economy, industrial output grew more than 11 per cent per annum between 1952 and 1978 (Table 9.1), while employment grew nearly tenfold, from 5.3 million in 1952 to 53.3 million in 1978 (Table 9.2).

In line with planners’ objectives, quantitative expansion brought a pronounced shift in the structure of industry, which moved away from formerly dominant consumer manufactures toward intermediate and producer products. Entirely new industries appeared—for example, manufacture of trucks, tractors, radios, telecom, and power-generating equipment. The rise of machinery, from only 6.2 per cent of industrial output in 1952 to 25.7 per cent in 1978 (Table 9.7), highlights the direction and magnitude of structural change. By the 1970s, the sectoral composition of industry resembled that of a country with significantly higher GDP per capita, such as Japan in the late 1950s.

Declining spatial concentration, a trend already visible between 1933 and 1952, continued in the socialist plan environment (Table 9.7). China’s first five-year plan (1953–7) concentrated investment in inland provinces, bypassing coastal regions that had dominated pre-war manufacturing. Planners also relocated personnel and factories from militarily vulnerable coastal cities to interior regions. Dispersion continued during the 1960s under the ‘Third Front’ programme, which situated industrial facilities in remote interior locations to guard against potential US or Soviet attacks (Naughton, 1988). With these shifts, the Herfindahl index for provincial industrial output continued the decline begun during the 1930s, falling from 0.09 in 1952 to 0.06 in 1978 (Table 9.4).

Beyond the cities, and largely outside the formal plan, development of rural industry represents an unusual feature of Chinese industrialization. Rural enterprises, most run by agricultural collectives, aimed to serve agriculture and to use local resources to satisfy local demand for cement, fertilizer, machinery, electricity, and coal. Promotion of rural industry began in the mid-1950s, experienced explosive but hugely wasteful growth during the Great Leap Forward (1958–60), and re-emerged in the late 1960s following major post-Leap retrenchment. By 1978, rural industry (including mining and construction as well as manufacturing) employed 19.7 million workers (Thirty Years, 2008, p. 248). Rural industry was particularly successful in the suburbs of major coastal cities that had also developed the largest non-agricultural sectors prior to 1949—that is, the regions disfavoured by both the early PRC investment plans and then by the Third Front policy.

By the 1970s, Chinese manufacturing, no longer limited to the production of low-end, labour-intensive consumer products, spanned virtually the entire range of industrial activity, including sophisticated operations involving petroleum refining, nuclear weapons, and earth satellites. Despite its brief duration, the flow of aid and trade from the USSR and its East European allies provided an unprecedented cross-national technology transfer that accelerated China’s effort to broaden the span of domestic manufacturing.8 Beyond the growth of output and extension of the product mix, socialist planning brought a vast expansion of industrial capabilities. The accumulation of production experience and the spread of mass education multiplied the stock of factory-level technical capabilities and human capital. In addition, the plan system underwrote a massive expansion of institutions, resources, and personnel for high-level technical training and research efforts. Ministries and major SOEs established networks of universities, technical schools, and R & D facilities. By the late 1970s, there were over 700 R & D institutes with over 500,000 scientists and engineers, nearly as many as in the United States (Gu, 1999, pp. 56–8; Nolting and Feshbach, 1981, p. 44).

Despite important advances, the achievements of Chinese industry during the plan era fell far short of potential. The most obvious indicator is slow productivity growth (World Bank, 1985, p. 110; Kuan et al., 1988), despite a long list of favourable circumstances: unprecedented official promotion of industrial development, large inflows of Soviet technology and capital goods, huge increases in public expenditure on R & D, and rapid expansion of primary education and basic health care.

Rising capital per worker—the consequence of steep increases in investment spending, much of it directed toward industry9—coincided with surprisingly slow growth of industrial output per worker—with several sectors, including metallurgy, suffering declines in labour productivity between 1965 and 1978 (Field, 1982). Factoring in improvements in human capital suggests negative TFP growth (Zhu, 2012). This ‘disappointing’ outcome meant that ‘rapid expansion of output came almost entirely from massive growth of labour and especially capital inputs’ (Chen et al., 1988, pp. 585–7). The obvious implication is that the beneficial impact of multiple sources of productivity growth was overwhelmed by institutional blockages and policy failures.10 With a rising share of GDP directed to investment to offset declining TFP, consumption languished.

Chinese observers were quick to highlight the institutional sources of poor outcomes. A 1982 editorial explained that ‘the basic causes of low [industrial] labour productivity’ included poor morale, bureaucratism and lax discipline ‘in many factories’ (Field, 1982, p. 656). Shigeru Ishikawa (1983, p. 275) highlighted shortcomings in the ‘investment goods sub-sector’, the core of the planned economy, which, despite receiving ‘an extremely high proportion of investment funds…[and] scarce foreign currency’, delivered weak results. ‘The marginal output-capital ratio…decreased considerably over time and hence the expected rise in the growth rate of national income [and other important results were]…not realized.’

Rawski (1975) and others replicated previous work on Soviet industry which showed how material-balance planning and ambitious physical output targets led managers to pursue quantity at the expense of quality, variety, innovation, cost, and customer satisfaction; to systematically overstate input requirements and understate production capacity; and to hoard materials, labour and backup production facilities. Naughton (1995, pp. 49–50) found that the accumulation of inventories and unfinished construction in China was considerably worse than in the USSR.

Specific Chinese policies added further impediments. Of particular importance in this connection was enforced self-sufficiency at the national, regional, and even local level, which limited both international and domestic trade and moved investment priorities far away from comparative advantage. Suspicion of intellectuals and technical expertise, which periodically stripped firms, government offices, schools, and research institutions of scarce and valuable talent, also came with high costs.

Beginning in the late 1970s, a succession of reform initiatives gradually led to a hybrid that combines important elements of planning, state ownership, and official direction with a revival of the open, private, market-based system of the 1920s and 1930s. This novel arrangement has extended the rapid growth attained under the former plan system, but combined quantitative expansion with market liberalization, deep integration with global markets, and rapid upgrading that has enabled a growing array of Chinese manufacturers to approach global frontiers of technical sophistication and product quality.

We separate the reform era into two periods, with 1995 as the break point.

China’s initial reforms included selective opening to the global economy, most notably through the establishment of Special Economic Zones (SEZs) that welcomed foreign investment and allowed duty-free import of materials used to manufacture export goods, as well as incremental reform of state-owned enterprises. The critical element in early-stage reform, however, was market liberalization, which advanced along multiple axes.

Price and quantity determination, formerly the near-exclusive preserve of official plan bodies, moved toward market outcomes. Separate initiatives empowering firms to arrange the disposition of above-quota output and establishing ‘dual pricing’, i.e. market pricing of non-plan exchanges, injected scarcity-based marginal values into a formerly rigid pricing system (Naughton, 1995). By 1991, ‘market forces’ had surpassed ‘state order’ in determining prices of ‘production materials’; in 1995, the share of market forces reached 77.9 per cent (Rawski, 2000, p. 320).

Introduction of partial profit retention (for firms) and bonuses (for workers) reversed the plan system’s destruction of incentives and weakened the corrosive impact of soft budget constraints among state-owned firms.

Reforms began to dismantle plan-era restrictions that had limited the mobility of people, goods, technology, funds, and information across China’s internal and international boundaries. These initiatives sparked what developed into vast flows of migrant labour to coastal industrial centres; they also undermined protectionist policies aimed at retaining local materials and blocking inflows of manufactures.

Finally, early reforms reduced impediments to entry and exit in a growing array of industries. Although SOE monopoly persisted in some sectors (Haggard and Huang, 2008), others opened up for entry by non-state actors—urban collectives, rural township and village enterprises (TVEs), private domestic ventures, and foreign-invested firms.

Notwithstanding the continuation of plan allocations and prices, the revival of incentives, domestic trade and market-determined prices allowed producers some scope to modify their product mix, choose among alternative suppliers or extend sales efforts into new markets without cumbersome bureaucratic approvals. New entrants, operating outside the plan system, could occupy market niches overlooked by the plan apparatus. Growing availability of materials and services outside the plan encouraged specialization, reversing the excessive vertical integration developed in the plan environment.

At the same time, growing openness steadily enlarged the global impact on China’s formerly isolated and largely self-reliant industrial sector, which faced the prospect of accessing a backlog of overseas innovations dating back to the 1930s. Manufactured exports rose over 100-fold in US dollar terms between 1978 and 1995 (Table 9.3). Imports were heavily weighted with capital equipment, raw materials, and, reflecting China’s growing participation in global supply chains, industrial components, most delivered to the factory sector.

FDI increased dramatically (Tables 9.5 and 9.9). Firms with Hong Kong and Taiwan ties, run by entrepreneurs with long experience in producing and exporting consumer products, were especially prominent, constituting the majority of enterprises in the SEZs. Specializing in the assembly and export of textiles, apparel, footwear, and electronics, these firms became the leading source of China’s exports. Nonetheless, the share of foreign-linked firms in industrial output (Table 9.5), the share of exports in sales of manufactured goods (Table 9.3), and the share of FDI in overall investment (Fixed Assets, 2002, p. 20) remained below 15 per cent throughout this period.

Table 9.9.

Inward and outward FDI (US$ billion)

Year199020002010

FDI inflow

 

3.48

 

40.71

 

105.70

 

FDI sources:

 
   

Asia

 
 

25.48

 
 

Hong Kong

 

1.91

 

15.50

 

60.60

 

Japan

 

0.50

 

2.92

 

0.71

 

Korea

 
 

1.49

 

2.70

 

Europe

 
 

4.76

 
 

Germany

 

0.02

 

1.04

 

0.89

 

UK

 

0.01

 

1.16

 

0.71

 

North America

 
 

4.78

 
 

US

 

0.46

 

4.38

 

3.02

 

Canada

 

0.41

 

0.28

 

0.71

 

FDI outflow

 

0.83

 

0.92

 

68.81

 

However, tariff and non-tariff barriers, remnants of the industrial plan system, ad hoc disruption of (especially private) business, and inadequate infrastructure (frequent power shortages, overcrowded railways, poor roads, primitive telecommunications) limited the economy’s response to these opportunities, just as similar domestic constraints had restricted the responsiveness of private actors during the decades prior to 1937.

Industrial growth during the early reform years was somewhat higher than during 1965–78 (Table 9.1), with big increases in the growth of textiles and food processing (Table 9.10). Although the share of machinery, chemicals, and metallurgy changed little between 1978 and 1995 (Table 9.7), industry shifted toward the same coastal provinces that had led the development of private sector manufacturing prior to the Second World War (Table 9.4) and, reflecting the tripling of China’s trade ratio from 11.8 to 38.7 per cent between 1978 and 1995 (Table 9.3), toward sectors and products in which China held a comparative advantage.

Table 9.10.

Real annual growth rates for gross output value, 1952–2008 (per cent)

1952–651965–781978–951995–2008

Sector

 
    

Metallurgy

 

18.4

 

7.4

 

10.3

 

14.7

 

Power

 

18.8

 

10.7

 

10.5

 

15.0

 

Coal and coke

 

10.9

 

7.5

 

5.9

 

9.5

 

Petroleum

 

27.4

 

14.8

 

4.7

 

5.9

 

Chemicals

 

22.8

 

13.6

 

12.7

 

13.9

 

Machinery

 

19.0

 

13.4

 

12.3

 

19.8

 

Building materials

 

11.9

 

11.6

 

14.7

 

10.7

 

Timber

 

4.9

 

3.9

 

8.5

 

14.8

 

Food and drink

 

6.8

 

5.7

 

10.7

 

11.4

 

Textiles

 

6.7

 

7.0

 

11.2

 

11.3

 

Paper

 

10.8

 

5.8

 

15.2

 

13.1

 

Total

 

12.3

 

10.2

 

11.6

 

13.8

 

Growth occurred primarily outside the state sector, reducing the SOE output share from 80 to 49 per cent between 1978 and 1995 (Industry, 1985, pp. 31–2; Table 9.5). TVEs emerged as a key source of fresh momentum. Concentrated in the once again dynamic coastal regions, these firms, largely owned and managed by township and village governments (although some were in reality private), absorbed labour released by the productivity growth that accompanied agricultural reform (Lin, 1992) and tapped expanding domestic trade networks to sell their products and obtain equipment, materials, and expertise. Powerful incentives, limited technical expertise, and hard budget constraints (Whiting, 2001) led TVEs to focus on labour-intensive consumer products. Flexible, ambitious, and aligned with China’s comparative advantage, TVEs quickly entered international markets, accounting for 16.3 per cent of aggregate exports in 1990 and 28.9 per cent in 1995 (Thirty Years, 2008, p. 326; Yearbook, 2014, p. 329).

As waves of new entrants slashed returns in the consumer sector, China’s leaders began to rethink the position of the state sector. Sectors like garments and beverages were designated as ‘competitive industries’—meaning that market competition could determine the fate of SOEs in those product lines. Planning increasingly focused on a limited array of ‘strategic’ sectors seen as deserving special attention and support. Despite the reforms, state firms in the secondary sector (industry and construction) absorbed over half (and often much more) of aggregate investment outlays in every year between 1981 and 1995.11 SOEs enjoyed priority access to bank lending. Licensing of advanced technology and joint ventures with overseas multinationals—for example, Beijing Jeep and Shanghai-Volkswagen—provided additional support for the expansion of SOE technical capabilities and competitiveness. Despite these advantages, SOEs lagged behind other firms in both financial returns (Holz, 2003, pp. 165–70) and productivity growth (Jefferson et al., 2000, pp. 797–804). This motivated efforts beginning in the mid-1990s to expand the reform effort.

On the domestic front, the government privatized (largely to insiders) or shut down large numbers of small, inessential or poorly performing SOEs: more than 75,000 SOE firms disappeared, and, with them, the jobs of 15–20 million workers. The state sector’s share of industrial output fell from 48.6 to 24 per cent between 1995 and 2008 (Table 9.5). The remaining SOEs were larger and increasingly concentrated in sectors like steel, precision machinery, and chemicals that the state identified as strategic or ‘pillar’ industries.

A series of policy initiatives sought to make the SOEs more commercial and more innovative. A State-Owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission (SASAC) was established to consolidate management of the state’s ownership interests and take the lead in restructuring major SOEs to boost their competitiveness (Naughton, 2015). The government poured resources into the promotion of ‘indigenous innovation’ that would establish China as a producer (rather than, as in the past, a purchaser) of cutting-edge technology. The state also pushed Chinese firms, with SOEs again in the forefront, to ‘go outward’ by increasing overseas direct investment (Table 9.9) in order to deepen market experience and accelerate both the absorption and the development of advanced technologies.

Legal reforms that explicitly affirmed the legitimacy of private enterprise encouraged the rapid expansion of privately owned manufacturing, involving both new enterprise formation and privatization of TVEs and urban collectives. Restrictions on the movement of people and goods were further eroded.

On the external front, multiple initiatives—falling tariffs and non-tariff barriers, fresh measures to encourage FDI, allowing large numbers of firms to engage in international trade, and more generous currency retention rights for exporters—culminated in China’s 2001 accession to the World Trade Organization (Lardy, 2002; Branstetter and Lardy, 2008). Reform leaders like Zhu Rongji saw a strong link between external and internal reforms. They viewed China’s WTO agreements as a ‘credible commitment’ to the continued pursuit of market outcomes to which domestic players, especially major SOEs, would be compelled to adjust. From this perspective, the domestic impact of external reforms may have exceeded the direct benefits of WTO entry.

Industrial growth accelerated during this period (Table 9.1). The output share of textiles and food processing continued to decline, while machinery’s share rose to almost half (Table 9.7).12 The southeast coast continued to advance, raising its output share to 45.8 per cent by 2008 (Table 9.4).

While manufactured exports grew rapidly, China’s rapidly expanding, highly competitive, and increasingly demanding domestic market absorbed over 80 per cent of incremental manufacturing output during both sub-periods of the reform era (Table 9.3). For most manufacturers, the opportunity to sell into this domestic market, the world’s largest for products ranging from autos to mobile phones and nuclear power equipment, provided the biggest boost to growth. Although market opening has allowed foreign-linked firms to gain ground in a number of sectors, domestic enterprises have achieved strong competitive positions, in some cases—beer, home appliances, heavy construction equipment—recapturing market share initially ceded to foreign operators. As of 2008, domestic firms accounted for over three-fourths of industrial output (Table 9.5).13

The reforms increased the incentives for firms to invest in capability building, as well as their ability to upgrade. Incremental innovation and upgrading allowed firms to narrow the productivity gap vis-à-vis domestic and international leaders, similar to recent developments elsewhere in Asia as well as China’s longer-term catch-up dating from the late nineteenth century. FDI, which accelerated following Deng Xiaoping’s southern trip (1992) and continued at high levels thereafter, was a major contributor (Table 9.9). A significant portion of the FDI originated from relatively small firms based in Hong Kong and Taiwan. Large multinationals like Boeing, General Electric, Hitachi, and Volkswagen also established substantial Chinese operations.

Foreign firms initially focused on using Chinese land and labour to reduce production costs for components and final goods sold overseas. ‘Processing’ exports, an arrangement that allows duty-free importation of materials and components, propelled Chinese engagement with global production chains. As foreign firms gained familiarity with the rising capabilities of Chinese manufacturers, they turned to domestic suppliers to source an increasing range of components and help lower costs. This multiplied the dispersion of international standards and advanced business practices (inventory management, production scheduling, quality control, etc.) among domestic manufacturers, as the supply chain of a single assembly plant for vehicles or electrical equipment can involve thousands of component and material vendors. Finally, in anticipation of rapidly rising incomes and a growing middle class, FDI was increasingly directed toward serving the growing domestic market, a shift that intensified competition in many domestic product categories.

The experience of Chinese firms in telecoms and construction equipment illustrates the contribution of openness and liberalization to industrial upgrading. Huawei, initially dismissed as technically weak by both Chinese planners and their MNE partners, followed the path of China’s pre-war ‘match king’ by building expertise in neglected markets—first in small cities in China’s interior and then in Africa—to develop innovative products that subsequently penetrated high-end markets both within and outside China (Brandt and Thun, 2013). Reflecting spillovers from China’s growing R & D expenditures (Hu and Jefferson, 2008), research engineers designed inexpensive concrete pumps that allowed Sany, an obscure Hunan start-up, to develop into an internationally competitive manufacture of construction equipment (Brandt and Thun, 2015).

Growing market penetration and rising unit values confirm the growing sophistication and rapid upward migration of Chinese manufactured exports along international price/quality ladders (Schott, 2008; Mandel, 2013). The domestic (Chinese) content of exports has increased significantly, reflecting a deepening of local supply chains and capabilities (Kee and Tang, 2016). Manufacturing productivity growth, largely coming from the entry of new firms, now parallels the achievements of other successful economies during periods of similarly rapid industrial expansion (Brandt, Van Biesebroeck, and Zhang, 2012). The most dynamic outcomes are in sectors that are highly contested and readily accessible to foreign investors, and which obstruct neither entry nor exit by domestic firms (Brandt, Rawski, and Sutton, 2008; Brandt and Thun, 2015; Brandt et al., 2012, revised 2015).

At the same time, there is large-scale inefficiency within individual sectors: Hsieh and Klenow (2009) conclude that reducing efficiency gaps between firms within sectors to levels observed in US manufacturing could have raised productivity in China’s factories by 30–50 per cent during 1998–2005. Preferential access to capital, energy and other key inputs is the likely culprit for these costs, which often show up in the form of excess capacity in firms and sectors. Table 9.11 reveals big differences in productivity dynamics between sectors with 1998 SOE output shares above or below 50 per cent. For sectors in which SOEs contributed the majority of 1998 output, outcomes are uniformly weak: continuing firms contribute negatively to productivity growth, as do new entrants, including new private firms—meaning that new firms enter with productivity levels below those of incumbents. For sectors with 1998 SOE shares below 50 per cent, the picture is the opposite, with productivity rising, primarily because entering firms deliver above-average results, thus boosting sector-wide outcomes.

Table 9.11.

Sectoral SOE shares and TFP growth, 1998–2007

SectorsTotal change in in TFPSources of change in TFPWithinBetweenEntryExit

SOE share > 0.50

 

−0.117

 

−0.048

 

0.007

 

−0.080

 

0.004

 

SOE share < 0.50

 

0.208

 

0.050

 

−0.024

 

0.175

 

0.007

 

All sectors

 

0.107

 

0.019

 

−0.014

 

0.096

 

0.006

 

Our survey ends with a profound contradiction. As China navigates the fourth decade of a transition that produced results beyond anyone’s wildest dreams, the strategy of placing state-owned firms at the core of the nation’s development plans, a constant feature of economic policy making dating from the Chiang Kai-shek administration of the 1930s, emerges yet again as an obstacle to the achievement of ambitious economic goals. With the current administration seemingly committed to the traditional policy of populating the economy’s commanding heights with state enterprises, we must ask whether the economy’s forward momentum will be sufficient to carry the costs associated with state ownership.

Since its inception during the second half of the nineteenth century, modern industry in China has amassed an enviable record of rapid growth. Only the Second World War halted the long-term expansion of output, and even then on-going capacity growth pushed output to unprecedented levels once hostilities came to an end.

China’s initial forays into manufacturing clustered around Shanghai and the southeastern coastal provinces, regions that subsequently maintained their leading position even as modern industry spread across China’s cities and penetrated into the countryside. Nineteenth-century industrialization combined official ventures oriented toward defence-related sectors and private efforts focused on mechanized processing of farm products. Following several decades of mainly private initiatives oriented toward labour-intensive consumer manufactures, Japan’s annexation of Manchuria in 1931 prompted a shift toward military-linked producer products and public ownership that continues to occupy a major plank of Chinese economic strategy.

Industrial expansion has involved qualitative change along with growing output volume. The initially narrow range of domestic manufactured goods has expanded dramatically. Chinese firms now populate every industrial segment. In a growing array of sectors, leading Chinese manufacturers can compete with leading multinationals. In sector after sector—yarn, machine tools, power generating equipment, computers—the transition of Chinese goods from laggards to formidable rivals follows a common path. Imports of novel products establish a market that domestic firms seek to penetrate. Their efforts, initially based on imitation, result in the production of cheap, low-quality domestic substitutes. Some of these producers of inferior goods mobilize sufficient capabilities to upgrade their products, thus beginning the ascent of that particular sector’s price–quality ladder.

Crucial for growth, capability accumulation, and upgrading are openness to international flows of goods, capital, people, technology, and ideas; domestic market liberalization; and supportive institutions. We see these as mutually reinforcing, although Chinese reality defies simple analysis, and there may be substitutes for these essential ingredients (for example, personal networks extending into the ranks of government and Communist Party officials may partially offset the absence of secure property rights in today’s PRC). The 1910s and 1920s saw substantial growth with minimal official support. Between 1949 and 1978, the PRC’s planned economy delivered both rapid growth and considerable expansion of capabilities with limited openness and no domestic liberalization. And the current reform era has produced an astonishing burst of growth and upgrading in the face of massive institutional deficits and considerably less openness or liberalization than existed in the early twentieth century.

The objective of ‘enriching the nation and strengthening the army’ motivated official behaviour throughout our period, though the capacity of the state to underwrite militarily significant industrial efforts expanded hugely under the PRC. The shift from market dominance toward state control, conventionally attributed to the inception of Soviet-type planning during the 1950s, actually began much earlier. Chiang Kai-shek’s Nanjing government began to embrace planning and state ownership from 1931; in the northeast, Japanese influence propelled a similar shift as early as the late 1910s. The question of the benefits and costs of state ownership, management, and control has thus permeated Chinese policy discussions during the past eighty years, and remains central today.

Looking ahead, we can anticipate continued deepening of industrial capabilities through multiple channels: domestic and overseas education, accumulation of production and marketing experience, increasing domestic R & D outlays, learning from large-scale inward and outbound FDI, and energetic, well-funded promotion of officially mandated nodes of ‘indigenous innovation’. At the same time, immense industrial advance coexists with staggering inefficiency, an outcome that extends across multiple institutional settings—extensive planning with near-total public ownership prior to 1978, the initial reform period of the 1980s and early 1990s, and the more open and further liberalized system of the last two decades.

This chapter resonates with a larger body of work that highlights state-owned industry as the chief contributor to the vast inefficiencies that litter China’s development path. It is not simply that SOEs, led by Communist Party appointees who must juggle (often conflicting) commercial and political objectives, have recorded consistently weak cost, profit, and productivity performance. We now have ample evidence that state ownership slows overall growth and impinges on financial stability and structural change.

China’s leaders are well aware of these costs, and presumably understand that on-going efforts to attack corruption, encourage strong firms to absorb weak rivals, and exhort participants to follow official priorities cannot succeed where past reforms have failed. However, the value to Chinese elites of a large and growing state sector, which provides a treasure house of patronage and rents as well as an army of powerful and responsive subordinates, banishes serious consideration of sweeping SOE privatization from the current policy agenda.

Will China’s on-going momentum continue to override the current system’s immense costs, maintaining something approaching the rapid progress of the past several decades? Might SOE giants slow the pace of innovation by blocking or absorbing potential rivals? Will SOE service oligopolies escalate system costs as the integration of telecoms and other services with manufacturing advances? Only time will tell.

Bian, M. L. ().

The Sino-Japanese War and the formation of the state enterprise system in China: a case study of the Dadukou iron and steel works, 1938–1945.

  3, 80–123.

Brandt, L. and Thun, E. ().

Going mobile in China: shifting value chains and upgrading in the mobile telecom sector.

 

International Journal of Technological Learning, Innovation and Development

4, 148–80.

Brandt, L., Rawski, T., and Sutton, J. (). China’s industrial development. In

China’s Great Economic Transformation

(Eds, Brandt, L. and Rawski, T.). Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 569–632.

Brandt, L., Van Biesebroeck, J., and Zhang, Y. F. ().

Creative accounting or creative destruction? Firm-level productivity growth in Chinese manufacturing.

 

Journal of Development Economics

97, 339–51.

Brandt, L., Van Biesebroek, J. L., Wang, L. H., and Zhang, Y. F. (2012, revised 2016). WTO accession and performance of Chinese manufacturing firms. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 9166.

Branstetter, L. and Lardy, N. R. (). China’s embrace of globalization. In

China’s Great Economic Transformation

(Eds, Brandt, L. and Rawski, T.). Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 633–82.

Cochran, S. G. (). Three roads into Shanghai’s market: Japanese, Western, and Chinese companies in the match trade, 1895–1937. In (Eds, Wakeman, F. and Yeh, W. H.). Berkeley, CA: Institute of East Asian Studies, 35–75.

Field, R. M. (). Real capital formation in the People’s Republic of China, 1952–73. In

Quantitative Measures of China’s Economic Output

(Ed., Eckstein, A.). Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 194–245.

Haggard, S. and Huang, Y. S. (). The political economy of private sector development in China. In

China’s Great Economic Transformation

(Eds, Brandt, L. and Rawski, T.). Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press, 337–74.

Hu, A. G. Z. and Jefferson, G. H. (). Science and technology in China. In

China’s Great Economic Transformation

(Eds, Brandt, L. and Rawski, T.). Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 286–336.

Jefferson, G. H., Rawski, T. G., Wang, L., and Zheng, Y. ().

Ownership, productivity change, and financial performance in Chinese industry.

 

Journal of Comparative Economics

28, 786–813.

Kuan, C., Hongchang, W., Yuxin, Z., Jefferson, G. H., and Rawski, T. G. ().

Productivity change in Chinese industry: 1963–1985.

 

Journal of Comparative Economics

12, 570–91.

Li, P. F., Bathelt, H., and Wang, J. ().

Network dynamics and cluster evolution: changing trajectories of the aluminium extrusion industry in Dali, China.

 

Journal of Economic Geography

12, 127–55.

Naughton, B. (). The transformation of the state sector: SASAC, the market economy, and the new national champions. In

State Capitalism, Institutional Adaptation, and the Chinese Miracle

(Eds, Naughton, B. and Tsai, K.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 46–71.

Rawski, T. G. (). China’s industrial system. In

China: A Reassessment of the Economy

(United States Congress, Joint Economic Committee). Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office, 175–98.

Rawski, T. G. (). China’s move to market: how far? what next? In

China’s Future: Constructive Partner or Emerging Threat?

(Eds, Carpenter, T. G. and Dorn, J. A.). Washington, DC: Cato Institute, 317–39.

Wang, Y. C. (). Secular trends of rice prices in the Yangzi Delta, 1638–1935. In

Chinese History in Economic Perspective

(Eds, Rawski, T. G. and Li, L. M.). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 35–68.

Wong, C. (). Material allocation and decentralization: impact of the local sector on industrial reform. In

The Political Economy of Reform in Post-Mao China

(Eds, Perry, E. J. and Wong, C.). Cambridge, MA: Council on East Asian Studies/Harvard University, 253–78.

Zhang, Y. F. [Chang, Y. F.] (). ‘

Qingmo Minchu de minying gongye

’ [Private sector industry during late Qing and under the early Republic]. Zhongyang yanjiuyuan jindaishi yanjiusuo jikan [

Quarterly Journal of the Modern History Institute of the Academia Sinica

] 18, 315–561.

Postingan terbaru

LIHAT SEMUA